-
(单词翻译:双击或拖选)
Urban land
Space and the city
Poor land use in the world's greatest cities carries a huge cost
BUY land, advised Mark Twain; they're not making it any more. In fact, land is not really scarce:
the entire population of America could fit into Texas with more than an acre for each household to enjoy.
What drives prices skyward is a collision between rampant1 demand and limited supply in the great metropolises3 like London, Mumbai and New York.
In the past ten years real prices in Hong Kong have risen by 150%. Residential4 property in Mayfair, in central London,
can go for as much as 55,000 (82,000) per square metre. A square mile of Manhattan residential property costs 16.5 billion.
Even in these great cities the scarcity5 is artificial. Regulatory limits on the height and density6 of buildings constrain7 supply and inflate8 prices.
A recent analysis by academics at the London School of Economics estimates that land-use regulations in the West End of London inflate the price of office space by about 800%; in Milan and Paris the rules push up prices by around 300%.
Most of the enormous value captured by landowners exists because it is well-nigh impossible to build new offices to compete those profits away.
The costs of this misfiring property market are huge, mainly because of their effects on individuals.
High housing prices force workers towards cheaper but less productive places.
According to one study, employment in the Bay Area around San Francisco would be about five times larger than it is but for tight limits on construction.
Tot up these costs in lost earnings9 and unrealised human potential, and the figures become dizzying.
Lifting all the barriers to urban growth in America could raise the country's GDP by between 6.5% and 13.5%, or by about 1 trillion-2 trillion.
It is difficult to think of many other policies that would yield anything like that.
Two long-run trends have led to this fractured market. One is the revival10 of the city as the central cog in the global economic machine.
In the 20th century, tumbling transport costs weakened the gravitational pull of the city; in the 21st, the digital revolution has restored it.
Knowledge-intensive industries such as technology and finance thrive on the clustering of workers who share ideas and expertise12.
The economies and populations of metropolises like London, New York and San Francisco have rebounded13 as a result.
What those cities have not regained14 is their historical ability to stretch in order to accommodate all those who want to come.
There is a good reason for that: unconstrained urban growth in the late 19th century fostered crime and disease.
Hence the second trend, the proliferation of green belts and rules on zoning.
Over the course of the past century land-use rules have piled up so plentifully15 that getting planning permission is harder than hailing a cab on a wet afternoon.
London has strict rules preventing new structures blocking certain views of St Paul's Cathedral.
Google's plans to build housing on its Mountain View campus in Silicon16 Valley are being resisted on the ground that residents might keep pets,
which could harm the local owl11 population. Nimbyish residents of low-density districts can exploit planning rules on everything from light levels to parking spaces to block plans for construction.
A good thing, too, say many. The roads and rails criss-crossing big cities already creak under the pressure of growing populations.
Dampening property prices hurts one of the few routes to wealth-accumulation still available to the middle classes.
A cautious approach to development is the surest way to preserve public spaces and a city's heritage: give economists17 their way,
and they would quickly pave over Central Park.
However well these arguments go down in local planning meetings, they wilt18 on closer scrutiny19. Home ownership is not especially egalitarian.
Many households are priced out of more vibrant20 places. It is no coincidence that the home-ownership rate in the metropolitan21 area of downtrodden Detroit,
at 71%, is well above the 55% in booming San Francisco. You do not need to build a forest of skyscrapers22 for a lot more people to make their home in big cities.
San Francisco could squeeze in twice as many and remain half as dense23 as Manhattan.
Property wrongs
Zoning codes were conceived as a way to balance the social good of a growing, productive city and the private costs that growth sometimes imposes.
But land-use rules have evolved into something more pernicious: a mechanism24 through which landowners are handed both unwarranted windfalls and the means to prevent others from exercising control over their property.
Even small steps to restore a healthier balance between private and public good would yield handsome returns. Policymakers should focus on two things.
First, they should ensure that city-planning decisions are made from the top down. When decisions are taken at local level, land-use rules tend to be stricter.
Individual districts receive fewer of the benefits of a larger metropolitan population (jobs and taxes) than their costs (blocked views and congested streets).
Moving housing-supply decisions to city level should mean that due weight is put on the benefits of growth.
Any restrictions25 on building won by one district should be offset26 by increases elsewhere, so the city as a whole keeps to its development budget.
Second, governments should impose higher taxes on the value of land. In most rich countries, land-value taxes account for a small share of total revenues.
Land taxes are efficient. They are difficult to dodge27; you cannot stuff land into a bank-vault in Luxembourg.
Whereas a high tax on property can discourage investment, a high tax on land creates an incentive28 to develop unused sites.
Land-value taxes can also help cater29 for newcomers. New infrastructure30 raises the value of nearby land, automatically feeding through into revenues—which helps to pay for the improvements.
Neither better zoning nor land taxes are easy to impose. There are logistical hurdles31, such as assessing the value of land with the property stripped out.
The politics is harder still. But politically tricky32 problems are ten-a-penny. Few offer the people who solve them a trillion-dollar reward.
1 rampant | |
adj.(植物)蔓生的;狂暴的,无约束的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
2 metro | |
n.地铁;adj.大都市的;(METRO)麦德隆(财富500强公司之一总部所在地德国,主要经营零售) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
3 metropolises | |
n.一国的主要城市(不一定是首都)( metropolis的名词复数 );中心;大都会;大城市 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
4 residential | |
adj.提供住宿的;居住的;住宅的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
5 scarcity | |
n.缺乏,不足,萧条 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
6 density | |
n.密集,密度,浓度 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
7 constrain | |
vt.限制,约束;克制,抑制 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
8 inflate | |
vt.使膨胀,使骄傲,抬高(物价) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
9 earnings | |
n.工资收人;利润,利益,所得 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
10 revival | |
n.复兴,复苏,(精力、活力等的)重振 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
11 owl | |
n.猫头鹰,枭 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
12 expertise | |
n.专门知识(或技能等),专长 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
13 rebounded | |
弹回( rebound的过去式和过去分词 ); 反弹; 产生反作用; 未能奏效 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
14 regained | |
复得( regain的过去式和过去分词 ); 赢回; 重回; 复至某地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
15 plentifully | |
adv. 许多地,丰饶地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
16 silicon | |
n.硅(旧名矽) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
17 economists | |
n.经济学家,经济专家( economist的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
18 wilt | |
v.(使)植物凋谢或枯萎;(指人)疲倦,衰弱 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
19 scrutiny | |
n.详细检查,仔细观察 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
20 vibrant | |
adj.震颤的,响亮的,充满活力的,精力充沛的,(色彩)鲜明的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
21 metropolitan | |
adj.大城市的,大都会的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
22 skyscrapers | |
n.摩天大楼 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
23 dense | |
a.密集的,稠密的,浓密的;密度大的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
24 mechanism | |
n.机械装置;机构,结构 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
25 restrictions | |
约束( restriction的名词复数 ); 管制; 制约因素; 带限制性的条件(或规则) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
26 offset | |
n.分支,补偿;v.抵消,补偿 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
27 dodge | |
v.闪开,躲开,避开;n.妙计,诡计 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
28 incentive | |
n.刺激;动力;鼓励;诱因;动机 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
29 cater | |
vi.(for/to)满足,迎合;(for)提供饮食及服务 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
30 infrastructure | |
n.下部构造,下部组织,基础结构,基础设施 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
31 hurdles | |
n.障碍( hurdle的名词复数 );跳栏;(供人或马跳跃的)栏架;跨栏赛 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
32 tricky | |
adj.狡猾的,奸诈的;(工作等)棘手的,微妙的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|